×
NewsDay

AMH is an independent media house free from political ties or outside influence. We have four newspapers: The Zimbabwe Independent, a business weekly published every Friday, The Standard, a weekly published every Sunday, and Southern and NewsDay, our daily newspapers. Each has an online edition.

Why a national moratorium for rural evictions is necessary

Opinion & Analysis
BY PHILLAN ZAMCHIYA I ARGUE for a moratorium on the continued rise of large-scale acquisitions of customary land for private ”investments“ in the marginalised rural areas of Zimbabwe to allow for a post-colonial democratic national resolution of the three issues articulated below. The latest such unchallenged trend is epitomised by the recently gazetted Statutory Instrument […]

BY PHILLAN ZAMCHIYA

I ARGUE for a moratorium on the continued rise of large-scale acquisitions of customary land for private ”investments“ in the marginalised rural areas of Zimbabwe to allow for a post-colonial democratic national resolution of the three issues articulated below. The latest such unchallenged trend is epitomised by the recently gazetted Statutory Instrument 50 of 2021. This Communal Land (Setting Aside of Land) (Chiredzi,) Notice, 2021) by Local Government, Rural and Urban Development minister orders about 12 000 people occupying or using 12 940 hectares of customary land in Chilonga communal area in Chiredzi to depart immediately and permanently. This is meant to pave way for lucerne grass farming by Dendairy Private Limited. This is a company in Zimbabwe which produces dairy products. For emphasis, this is not an isolated case, as land rights holders — vulnerable women and men living on marginal customary land — face similar types of evictions in marginal places like Hwange and Chipinge districts.

Now to the reasons.

First, the government is partly basing its decision on a narrow belief that private big estates are the only  vehicle for economic transformation despite widespread evidence to their detrimental effects on the vulnerable people’s diverse livelihoods on the African continent. In line with this narrow pathway, the  Local Government minister, July Moyo, romanticised such land acquisition in Chilonga as a way to ensure big livestock production and generate foreign currency for the nation. Conversely, the  government portrays modes of production by the Shangaan people in Chilonga as pristine and unable  to drive economic rural development. This approach is problematic because it is premised on a narrow development transition pathway that envisions big companies (like Dendairy Pvt Ltd) led farming in the countryside as the only viable model or the real deal. The logic also reflects some of the flawed modernisation narratives of the colonial era, 40 years after gaining independence from British colonial rule. However, from the rich empirical data on livelihoods gathered by Masvingo Centre for Research Advocacy and Development (MACRAD, p3) the people of Chilonga are already involved in diverse  crop farming and livestock production. They are producing sorghum ( xibedlani, xitishi and mutode), millet (mahuvu and mpowo), some maize, sweet potatoes, cotton, pumpkins (mandunghu) and groundnuts (timanga). They also own cattle, sheep and close to 100% of the households own goats. Why then would the government choose to destroy and disrupt local livelihoods?

One alternative pathway to rural development would also require an emphasis on development projects that ensure that men and women living in rural areas do not lose their customary land. For the avoidance  of doubt, this is not an argument to maintain the status quo, or to preserve low productivity in Zimbabwe’s marginalised rural areas. For those who intend to create a straw man, I am not saying private investments in agriculture in the countryside should be eschewed. Rather, I am envisioning an  alternative pathway where investments will be directed towards ends that lead to people-centred and people-driven rural development in line with their developmental needs. It is a scenario in which the Agriculture ministry, for example, channel massive agricultural investment into the support of diverse livelihoods, crop and livestock farming activities by the people of Chilonga. I am inclined to  apply de Schutter (2011, p. 262)’s logic in this case. That the people of Chilonga can better be helped by private investments upstream and downstream of their production process of small grains and livestock, focusing on the provision of public goods that can improve productivity and access to  markets, and on institutional innovations that can strengthen their position and allow them to obtain better earnings in ways that enable them to reinvest for expanded reproduction and, therefore, contributing to wider economic development. A moratorium would allow the nation space to envision  such alternative rural development models as viable options.

Second, Zimbabwe’s land laws do not explicitly mention the right to consent in line with the universal principle of free prior informed consent (FPIC) and the Constitution. A moratorium would allow the government to entrench the universal right to self-determination in order  to protect vulnerable communities such as the people of Chilonga. The current land laws give power to  the President, local authorities and traditional leaders and responsible ministers to act on behalf of men  and women who live on customary land. This limits the power of the actual land holders to say  yes or no to development projects. The outdated Communal Lands Act does not explicitly mention the need to seek consent from the communities. FPIC is an international principle that gives people the right to say yes or no to developmental projects, therefore, upholding the universal right to self-determination (FAO 2014, p.12). FPIC at a policy implementation level, entails that the rights-holders, men and women, must make decisions free from undue influence, coercion, bribe or fear. Prior means  that consent must be sought before the project starts and that there should be sufficient time to make a  decision before the commencement of the investment project. In addition, the rights-bearers must be  informed before making a decision. That means having accurate, understandable, accessible and  complete information about the investment on an on-going basis.

Finally, consent refers to the collective decision made by the rights-holders (including women, youths and people with disabilities) which can  be a yes or a no or a conditional yes and can be revisited during the different stages of the investment  project. None of those principles were applied to the vulnerable land rights holders — men and women of Chilonga.

On a comparative basis, South Africa has an explicit (albeit temporary) law that entrenches the FPIC  principle that govern the acquisition of customary land. The Interim Protection of Informal Land Rights Act (IPILRA) of 1996 is meant to protect informal rights to land such as the right to use, gain access to or to occupy land under customary law in the former homeland areas. Consequently, IPILRA requires that the holder of informal land rights must consent to dispose of such a right. Section 4 notes that the  land right “can only be disposed by a majority of the holders of such right present or represented  at a meeting convened for the purpose of considering such disposal and of which they have been given  sufficient notice, and in which they have had a reasonable opportunity to participate.” South Africa’s  jurisprudence has strengthened the right to give consent. In 2018, the North Gauteng High Court ruled that the Xolobeni community in Eastern Cape, has a right to say no to a mining project, in line with IPLRA and the international principle of FPIC.Govt of Zimbabwe issued notice announcing eviction of over 12,000 people in Chiredzi. – KMAUPDATES

Third, even in the context of the Zimbabwean State using its expropriation powers, as happens  elsewhere, the current compensation model for customary land reinforces a pervasive neo-colonial  policy line that casts land under customary tenure as being of little or no economic value. Or what De Soto (2002) infamously termed “dead capital”. A moratorium would allow the nation to revisit the  compensation model. Where rural inhabitants have lost land held under customary tenure such as in  Chisumbanje for biofuel production or for Tugwi-Mukosi dam in Masvingo, State officials have  routinely contended that investors are only obliged to pay for improvements on the land, rather than the  land itself. This practice prevails despite the 2013 constitutional recognition of customary land rights. Policymakers mistakenly fail to fully recognise customary land rights because such rights are not  formally registered, ultimately depriving affected communities of fair and adequate compensation.  However, not only is land undervalued, so too is the value of agricultural and other productive activities such as hunting and gathering by the affected people of Chilonga, in a context where neither the market  value nor cost of restoring diverse rural livelihoods is clear. The current trend is one of underplaying losses in the wider ecosystem. Equally important is the understating of non-monetary losses in contemporary compensation models. Non-material losses are central to human development such as  cultural rights, identity and citizenship, belonging, history and memory. In Chilonga, there are a number  of sacred hills and areas such as Chigwejiva Sala for rainmaking ceremonies and cultural  activities. All that is not explicitly modelled in Zimbabwe’s current compensation system.

I, therefore, emphasise the need for the government to put a moratorium on rural evictions until the nation can collectively revisit this narrow pathway to rural development based on an envisioned  teleological transition to big private investors acquiring huge tracts of customary land in the marginal  areas as in the colonial era. A moratorium would: (a) allows the nation to debate and promote an  alternative rural development model that protects customary land rights for vulnerable men and women without taking away their land; (b) allows for the entrenchment of the right to self-determination in line with the universal principle of FPIC and (c) provide space for an evaluation of the current compensation models for loss of customary land, land rights and wider livelihoods and cultural rights.

The three ideas suggested here are not exhaustive but are big propositions that can lead to securing customary land rights for vulnerable women and men in the marginal areas (like the people of Chilonga) and foster inclusive rural development, particularly in the context of a renewed rush for “cheap” customary land in Zimbabwe by local and foreign investors.

  • Phillan Zamchiya is a political scientist who studied at University of Oxford, in England